Essay Available:
page:
9 pages/≈2475 words
Sources:
13
Style:
APA
Subject:
Business & Marketing
Type:
Research Paper
Language:
English (U.S.)
Document:
MS Word
Date:
Total cost:
$ 46.66
Topic:
Macroeconomic tools explaining the Great Depression of the 1930s
Research Paper Instructions:
Also, I need 13 sources. If this is a problem, let me know and ill change my order
“Use the macroeconomic tools surveyed in ECON 202 to explain the Great Depression of the 1930s, and comment on the extent to which this historical episode is relevant (if at all) for modern policy makers”.
also, the comments on modern policy makers should be 2-3 pages.
ill attach the notes from my class. the diagrams are not in there though
Suggested readings
(You should note that you are not required to consult all of these references, and, indeed, I suggest that you read at length only those references with which you feel comfortable. You are also expected to discover additional references. I will post additional references on blackboard).
Anderson, B. and Butkiewicz, J. 2001. “Money, Spending and the Great Depression” Southern Economic Journal. 47 (2) 388-403.
Anonymous. 1998. “A Refresher on the 1930s”. The Economist. September 19. p 94. [A conservative's interpretation of the Great Depression]
Bernanke, B. S. 1983. “Non-monetary Effects of the Financial Crisis in the Propagation of the Great Depression”. American Economic Review. 73. 257-6.
Bolch, B. 2001. “The Great Depression: Delayed Recovery and Economic Change in America, 1929-1939”. Southern Economic Journal. 55 (4) 1058-9.
Brown, E. C. 1956. “Fiscal Policy in the Thirties: A Re-appraisal”. American Economic Review. 46 857-879.
Blanchard, O. and Sheen, J. 2004. Macroeconomics. Australian Edition. Prentice Hall. Chapter 22.
Calomiris, C.W. 1993. “Financial Factors in the Great Depression”. Journal of Economic Perspectives. 7(2). pp 61-85.
Christiano, L. Motto, R. and Rostagno M. 2004. “The Great Depression and the Fiedman Schwartz Hypothesis”. Frankfurt. European Central Bank.
Cecchetti, S. 1992. “Prices During the Great Depression: Was the Deflation From the 1930-2 Really Unanticipated”. American Economic Review. 82 (1) 142.
Cecchetti, S. 1997. “Understanding the Great Depression: Lessons for Current Policy”. National Bureau of Economics Research. pp 1-26.
Christiano, L. Motto, R. 2004 “The Great Depression and the Friedman-Schwartz Hypothesis”. Society for Computational Economics. 169.
Cole, H. and Ohanian, L. E. 1999. “The Great Depression and the United States from a Neoclassical Perspective”. Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly Review. 23 (Winter) pp 2-24.
Cole, H. and Ohanian, L. E. 2002. “The U.S. and U.K. Great Depression Through the Lens of Neoclassical Growth Theory.” American Economic Review. 92 (2) 28-32.
Cooper, R and Corbae, D. 2002. “Financial Collapse from the Great Depression”. Journal of Economic Theory. 107. pp 159-190.
Darby, M. 1976. “Three and a Half Million U.S. Employees have Been Mislaid, or an Explanation of Unemployment, 1934-1941”. Journal of Political Economy. 1. pp 1-16.
Dimand, R, W. 2005. “Fisher, Keynes and the Corridor of Stability”. American Journal of Economics and Sociology. 64 (1) 185-199.
Fackler, J. S. and Parker, R.E. 1994. “Accounting For the Great Depression: A Historical Decomposition” Journal of Macroeconomics. 16 (2). pp 193-220.
Fisher, I. 1933. “The Debt Deflation Theory of Great Depressions”. Econometrica. 1 (4). Pp 337-357.
Friedman, M and R. 1980. Friedman. Free to Choose. Macmillan. Melbourne. Chapter 3. (NB This book has many editions and any edition will do). Chapter 3.
Friedman, M. and A.J. Schwartz, 1962. A Monetary History of United States. Princeton University Press. Princeton. Chapter 7.
Galbraith, J.K. 1954. The Great Crash 1929. Houghton Miffen Company. Boston. (NB This book has many editions and any edition will do).
Gordon, R.J. 1987. Macroeconomics. 4th edition. (NB Very nearly all of this text is relevant, but 7.3 is specifically on the Great Depression).
Formani, R. 2005. “Did the Fed Cause the Great Depression”. Liberty. 19 (3). (See web-site).
Greasley, D. Madson J. D. and Oxley, L. 2001. “Income Uncertainty and Consumer spending During the Great Depression”. Explorations in Economic History. 38. pp 225-251.
Hamilton, J. D. 1987. “Monetary Factors in the Great Depression”. Journal of Monetary Economics. 13 pp 1-25.
Koppl, R. 1991. “Retrospective: Animal Spirits”. Journal of Economic Perspectives. 5 (3) 203-210.
Krugman, P. 1999. “The Return of Depression Economics”. Foreign Affairs. 78. pp 56-74.
Mankiw, N.G.2003. Macroeconomics. Worth Publishers. (NB Very nearly all of this text is relevant, but 11.3 is specifically on the Great Depression).
Margo, R.A. 1993. “Employment and Unemployment in the 1930s”.Journal of Economic Perspectives. 7(2). pp 41-59.
Metzler, A. 1981. “Keynes' General Theory: A different Perspective”. Journal of Economic Literature. pp 34-64.
Minsky, H. P. 2001. “Did Monetary Forces Cause the Great depression?”. Challenge. 44-66.
Robert, P. C. and Stratton, L. M. 2001. “The Fed's Depression and the Birth of the New Deal”. Policy Review. 108 pp 19-33.
Romer, C. D. 1990. “The Great Crash and the Onset of the Great Depression”. Quarterly Journal of Economic Perspectives. 105 (3), pp 597-624.
Romer, C.D. 1993. “The Nation in Depression”. Journal of Economic Perspectives. 7(2). pp 19-39.
Romer, C. D. and Romer D. H. 1989. “Does the Policy Matter? A New Test in the Spirit of Friedman and Schwartz”. NBER Macroeconomic Annual. 4 pp 121-170.
Renshaw, P. 1999. “Was there a Keynesian Economy in the USA between 1933 and 1945”. Journal of Contemporary History. 34 337-364
Samuelson, R. J. 2001. “Ghosts of Booms Past”. The Washington Post. p 23.
Samuelson, R. J. 2003. “The Bogeyman of Deflation”. Newsweek. 19 May. p 42.
Snowden, B and H. R. Vane. 2005. Modern Macroeconomics. Its Origins. Development and Current State. Edward Elgar. Chapters 2 & 3
Temin, P. 1989. Lessons from the Great Depression. MIT Press. Cambridge, Mass.
Temin, P. 1993. “Transmission of the Great Depression”. Journal of Economic Perspectives. 7(2). pp 87-102.
Temin, P. 1990. “Socialism and Wages in the Recovery From the Great Depression in the United States and Germany”. Journal of Economic History. 50 (2) 297-307.
Trescott, P. 1992. “The Failure of the Bank of the U.,S. 1930”. Money Credit and Banking. 24 (3) 384-5.
Wallis, J.J. “Employment, Politics and Economic Recovery during the Great Depression”. The Review of Economics and Statistics. 69. pp 516-520.
Whicker, E. 1980. “A Reconsideration of the Causes of ther Banking Panic of 1930”. Journal of Economic History. 40 (3) 571-583.
White, E. N. 1990. “The Stock Market Boom and Crash of 1929 Revisited”. Journal of Economic Perspectives. 4(2). pp Yes
Simon
2011-10-01
Research Paper Sample Content Preview:
Running head: Business and Marketing
Macroeconomic tools explaining the Great Depression of the 1930s
University:
Name:
Course:
Tutor:
Date:
Macroeconomic tools explaining the Great Depression of the 1930s
The Great Depression is considered as the deepest, longest and most severe economic depression that hit the Western countries from 1929 to 1939. The effects were experienced across the world and it one of the worst economic calamities in the world’s history. In the depressions that had occurred previously like in the 1870s and 1890s, the real per capita gross domestic product (GDP) managed to return to their former levels within a span of five years (Christiano & Motto, 2004). However, the real per capita GDP in the 1930’s Great Depression was still lower than its 1929 level even after a period of ten years. This document will use macroeconomic tools to explain the Great Depression of the 1930s and the relevance of the episode to modern policy makers.
Episodes in the Great depression
Before the 1930s, a huge percentage of economic analysis was limited to microeconomics. Even in his book “The Wealth of Nations”, Adam Smith argued that the government should not interfere with market forces and customers should be allowed to make their individual choices (Galbraith, 2009). However, the 1930s Great Depression acted as a turning point prompting economists to analyze factors behind unemployment, money supply and other macroeconomic factors affecting the economy. In the 1920s, there was a boom in the U.S. stock market due to general optimism among economists and businessmen (Blanchard & Sheen, 2004). They firmly believed that the newly established Federal Reserve would lead to economic stabilization and that the upward trend in technological innovation will enhance the expanding markets and the rising standards of living. However, initial recession was brought by attempts by the U.S. Federal Reserve to raise interest rates in 1928 and 1929 so as to discourage stock speculation.
G-7 GDP in the Great Depression (Galbraith, 2009)
This caught most businesses and firms by surprise, creating a contagious effect that negatively impacted the whole economy. For instance, businesses cut down the plans they had made on further purchase of producer durable goods. On the other hand, companies which dealt in producer durables reduced their production capacities. Consumers who had lost their jobs as well as those who feared they would be retrenched reduced their purchases of consumer durables. Lastly, businesses which produced consumer durables were exposed to declining demand due to the actions of consumers (Galbraith, 2009). During the Great Depression, decline in prices, leading to deflation, initiated contraction effects in production which in turn led to addition decline in commodity prices.
During this time, the rate of decline in prices was 10% per annum, and calculations made by investors revealed that less profit would be earned if investments were done this year compared to next year when there would be a further 10% stretch of the dollar. As the international monetary system collapsed, panics continued to escalate within banking circles and doubt was cast on people’s credit (Cooper & Corbae, 2002). This reinforced the perception that was on the minds of the general public that it was time to ‘watch and wait’. Throughout the presidential term of Herbert Hoover, the slide to Depression was worsened by falling production, increased unemployment and falling prices.
A fully satisfactory explanation is yet to be given on why the depression occurred at this particular moment. If there was a possibility of such depressions occurring in a capitalist economy that is unregulated, why didn’t two or more Great depressions occur prior to the Second World War? Anna Schwartz and Milton Friedman argued that Depression is attributed to incredible sequence of blunders especially within the monetary policy (Greasley et al 2003). However, individual who were in control of the monetary policy during the early 1930s believed that they were using similar gold-standard rules as the ones used by their predecessors. If the individuals were wrong, why did they assume that their policies were similar to those used by their predecessors? On the other hand, if the individuals were correct, why was the Great Depression the only one of its kind? Both monetary and fiscal policies are needed to answer these fundamental questions (Okun, 1983). At the lowest point of the Depression, the situation almost became a collective insanity.
The first macroeconomic factor to be severely affected was employment. People remained idle since companies could not employ them to utilize their machines. Companies lacked the capacity of hiring workers to manage their machines due to unavailability of market for goods. The lack of market was caused by lack of income to spend among workers. In “The Road to Wigan Pier”, Orwell narrates who the effects of depression on employment in Britain (Christiano & Motto, 2004). He says that a huge number of men and women risked their lives by spending several hours scrambling in the mud looking for minute chips of coal for heating their houses. This free coal gained with difficulty was almost of much significance than food. Machinery that stood idle around them had the ability of doing more in five minute compared to what all people did that whole day. The Great Depression put a serious doubt on the survival of the political order and the viability of the economic system.
Monetary policy was another fundamental factor that was behind the 1930’s Great Depression. As already mentioned, the stock market in America boomed in the 1920s. The price levels reached a place where they stopped making sense based on the rules of thumb or traditional patterns for valuation. Several research studies argue that in September 1929, there was a market peak with 40% of stock market value not being justified by financial or economic analysis (Blanchard & Sheen, 2004; Greasley et al 2003). The Federal Reserve became concern with the high valuation in the stock market. There was a worrying feeling that a “bubble” constituent of the stock prices will suddenly burst. To start with, if the burst occurred, certain sections of the financial systems could be declared bankrupt, there would be damage in the network of financial intermediation, and investment would decline and consequently lead to recession. Therefore, the Federal Reserve decided to “cool off” the market raising interest rates to make borrowing money for stock speculation more expensive and difficult. However, they already knew that the rise in interest rates may lead to recession which they were trying to avoid by “cooling off” the market.
The U.S. macroeconomic indicators: The Great Contraction (Galbraith, 2009)
This implies that all policy options which at the disposal of Federal Reserve had some possibility of leading to negative consequences (Galbraith, 2009). In the subsequent years, Friedrich Hayek, a leading economist, argued that the Federal Reserve was behind the boom in the stock market, its subsequent crash and the Great Depression due to “easy money” policies. He adds that this action only prolonged a boom for another two years beyond its natural end. The collapse of the U.S. stock market in October 1929 was a clear indication that the economy had already passed the peak of the business cycle. The big worry of excessive speculation within the Federal Reserve led to unwarranted deflationary policies, leading to the adage: “destroying the village in order to save it” (Bolch, 2001). Therefore, after the stock market ultimately crashed in 1929, the first effect to take place was economic uncertainty about the next effect. Therefore, the most natural thing to do when something which most people do not understand occurs is to pause and wait until the event is made clearer.
Panic, debt and deflation
Throughout the whole period of depression, production per worker declined by more than 40% compared to what had been attained in 1929 (Davidson, 2009). Even as the level of unemployment consumed more than a quarter of American jobs, the government initially failed to stimulate ...
Macroeconomic tools explaining the Great Depression of the 1930s
University:
Name:
Course:
Tutor:
Date:
Macroeconomic tools explaining the Great Depression of the 1930s
The Great Depression is considered as the deepest, longest and most severe economic depression that hit the Western countries from 1929 to 1939. The effects were experienced across the world and it one of the worst economic calamities in the world’s history. In the depressions that had occurred previously like in the 1870s and 1890s, the real per capita gross domestic product (GDP) managed to return to their former levels within a span of five years (Christiano & Motto, 2004). However, the real per capita GDP in the 1930’s Great Depression was still lower than its 1929 level even after a period of ten years. This document will use macroeconomic tools to explain the Great Depression of the 1930s and the relevance of the episode to modern policy makers.
Episodes in the Great depression
Before the 1930s, a huge percentage of economic analysis was limited to microeconomics. Even in his book “The Wealth of Nations”, Adam Smith argued that the government should not interfere with market forces and customers should be allowed to make their individual choices (Galbraith, 2009). However, the 1930s Great Depression acted as a turning point prompting economists to analyze factors behind unemployment, money supply and other macroeconomic factors affecting the economy. In the 1920s, there was a boom in the U.S. stock market due to general optimism among economists and businessmen (Blanchard & Sheen, 2004). They firmly believed that the newly established Federal Reserve would lead to economic stabilization and that the upward trend in technological innovation will enhance the expanding markets and the rising standards of living. However, initial recession was brought by attempts by the U.S. Federal Reserve to raise interest rates in 1928 and 1929 so as to discourage stock speculation.
G-7 GDP in the Great Depression (Galbraith, 2009)
This caught most businesses and firms by surprise, creating a contagious effect that negatively impacted the whole economy. For instance, businesses cut down the plans they had made on further purchase of producer durable goods. On the other hand, companies which dealt in producer durables reduced their production capacities. Consumers who had lost their jobs as well as those who feared they would be retrenched reduced their purchases of consumer durables. Lastly, businesses which produced consumer durables were exposed to declining demand due to the actions of consumers (Galbraith, 2009). During the Great Depression, decline in prices, leading to deflation, initiated contraction effects in production which in turn led to addition decline in commodity prices.
During this time, the rate of decline in prices was 10% per annum, and calculations made by investors revealed that less profit would be earned if investments were done this year compared to next year when there would be a further 10% stretch of the dollar. As the international monetary system collapsed, panics continued to escalate within banking circles and doubt was cast on people’s credit (Cooper & Corbae, 2002). This reinforced the perception that was on the minds of the general public that it was time to ‘watch and wait’. Throughout the presidential term of Herbert Hoover, the slide to Depression was worsened by falling production, increased unemployment and falling prices.
A fully satisfactory explanation is yet to be given on why the depression occurred at this particular moment. If there was a possibility of such depressions occurring in a capitalist economy that is unregulated, why didn’t two or more Great depressions occur prior to the Second World War? Anna Schwartz and Milton Friedman argued that Depression is attributed to incredible sequence of blunders especially within the monetary policy (Greasley et al 2003). However, individual who were in control of the monetary policy during the early 1930s believed that they were using similar gold-standard rules as the ones used by their predecessors. If the individuals were wrong, why did they assume that their policies were similar to those used by their predecessors? On the other hand, if the individuals were correct, why was the Great Depression the only one of its kind? Both monetary and fiscal policies are needed to answer these fundamental questions (Okun, 1983). At the lowest point of the Depression, the situation almost became a collective insanity.
The first macroeconomic factor to be severely affected was employment. People remained idle since companies could not employ them to utilize their machines. Companies lacked the capacity of hiring workers to manage their machines due to unavailability of market for goods. The lack of market was caused by lack of income to spend among workers. In “The Road to Wigan Pier”, Orwell narrates who the effects of depression on employment in Britain (Christiano & Motto, 2004). He says that a huge number of men and women risked their lives by spending several hours scrambling in the mud looking for minute chips of coal for heating their houses. This free coal gained with difficulty was almost of much significance than food. Machinery that stood idle around them had the ability of doing more in five minute compared to what all people did that whole day. The Great Depression put a serious doubt on the survival of the political order and the viability of the economic system.
Monetary policy was another fundamental factor that was behind the 1930’s Great Depression. As already mentioned, the stock market in America boomed in the 1920s. The price levels reached a place where they stopped making sense based on the rules of thumb or traditional patterns for valuation. Several research studies argue that in September 1929, there was a market peak with 40% of stock market value not being justified by financial or economic analysis (Blanchard & Sheen, 2004; Greasley et al 2003). The Federal Reserve became concern with the high valuation in the stock market. There was a worrying feeling that a “bubble” constituent of the stock prices will suddenly burst. To start with, if the burst occurred, certain sections of the financial systems could be declared bankrupt, there would be damage in the network of financial intermediation, and investment would decline and consequently lead to recession. Therefore, the Federal Reserve decided to “cool off” the market raising interest rates to make borrowing money for stock speculation more expensive and difficult. However, they already knew that the rise in interest rates may lead to recession which they were trying to avoid by “cooling off” the market.
The U.S. macroeconomic indicators: The Great Contraction (Galbraith, 2009)
This implies that all policy options which at the disposal of Federal Reserve had some possibility of leading to negative consequences (Galbraith, 2009). In the subsequent years, Friedrich Hayek, a leading economist, argued that the Federal Reserve was behind the boom in the stock market, its subsequent crash and the Great Depression due to “easy money” policies. He adds that this action only prolonged a boom for another two years beyond its natural end. The collapse of the U.S. stock market in October 1929 was a clear indication that the economy had already passed the peak of the business cycle. The big worry of excessive speculation within the Federal Reserve led to unwarranted deflationary policies, leading to the adage: “destroying the village in order to save it” (Bolch, 2001). Therefore, after the stock market ultimately crashed in 1929, the first effect to take place was economic uncertainty about the next effect. Therefore, the most natural thing to do when something which most people do not understand occurs is to pause and wait until the event is made clearer.
Panic, debt and deflation
Throughout the whole period of depression, production per worker declined by more than 40% compared to what had been attained in 1929 (Davidson, 2009). Even as the level of unemployment consumed more than a quarter of American jobs, the government initially failed to stimulate ...
Get the Whole Paper!
Not exactly what you need?
Do you need a custom essay? Order right now:
👀 Other Visitors are Viewing These APA Essay Samples:
-
Consumer Interview
2 pages/≈550 words | 4 Sources | APA | Business & Marketing | Research Paper |
-
Training and development. Transference of Training
7 pages/≈1925 words | 4 Sources | APA | Business & Marketing | Research Paper |
-
The Effect of marketing communication to brand loyalty in Cadbury Company
4 pages/≈1100 words | 4 Sources | APA | Business & Marketing | Research Paper |